Whether we are on the cusp of another stagflation era is not just a question of semantics. Stagflation is painful for households, especially at the lower end of the income distribution, because it combines reduced purchasing power with weak employment opportunities. It also raises challenges for central bankers, as attempts to rein in inflation will further hurt growth and the labor market in the short run.

To assess stagflation risk, it’s useful to put some definition to the term. A simple rule of thumb might be to consider the combination of quarterly annualized inflation above three percent, and quarterly annualized real GDP growth below one percent, as stagflation. Growth need not be negative – a rate moderately below trend would likely weaken the labor market. Importantly though, under stagflation, weak growth and high inflation are persistent. Stagflation is, ultimately, a period of stagnation in overall economic wellbeing, one that becomes defined by its pernicious combination of rising prices, weak growth and limited employment outcomes. It is not a point in time, but a trend that impacts household and business decisions about spending and saving.

How often has the US experienced stagflation? Figure 2 below shows all combinations of quarterly growth and inflation since 1948. The upper-left quadrant denotes stagflationary outcomes, as defined above. What stands out is that in US post-war history, stagflation mainly occurred in one period, from 1969 to 1982. During these years, over a third of the time the US economy registered a stagflationary outcome.

Figure 2: Quarterly Real Growth and Inflation Outcomes (AR) | 1947-2019 and 3Q 2021

The stagflation of the 1970s was most importantly characterized by a negative supply shock resulting from two sustained oil price increases, one starting in 1973 and the other in 1979. These oil price shocks served as a significant tax on household income that weakened consumer spending. Meanwhile, businesses pulled backed on production and hiring due to higher energy costs. Other factors contributed to the high inflation at the time. Both monetary and fiscal policy had been very accommodative for years as the 1970s began, and the Bretton Woods system that linked the dollar to gold collapsed in 1971. In addition, the Federal Reserve largely looked through the first oil shock and focused on supporting economic activity. This policy response may have alleviated some of the growth and employment consequences of the negative supply shock, but added to inflation pressures.

That the stagflation of that era was driven in large part by a persistent and negative supply shock holds lessons for today. Certainly a good portion of the current mix of elevated inflation and slowing activity stems from supply constraints. Globally, output has been slow to pick up after the systematic lockdowns of early 2020. That some countries still resort to lockdowns, even if on a targeted basis, continues to hinder global production and supply chains. And the ongoing health crisis stands in the way of a more robust recovery in labor force participation, not least in the U.S. Meanwhile, higher prices are now weighing on household spending in some goods categories.

But importantly, these factors should be temporary. Over the course of the next year or so, global output should continue to recover, and logistics and supply chain bottlenecks should clear. Labor force participation will likely rise as vaccine rollout continues and better treatments become available. At the same time, the strong demand for cars, household furnishings and other durable goods that has contributed to supply-demand imbalances should fade in the absence of additional household stimulus checks and as spending rotates back towards services. All of this will take time, but there is little reason to think that current supply constraints represent a long-term negative supply shock for the global economy.

In contrast to a persistent 1970s-style supply shock, the years ahead are much more likely to see a robust expansion, with both growth and inflation above pre-pandemic trends. If anything, the outlook is reminiscent of the 1950s and early 1960s, with fiscal policy used more assertively to support household income, and monetary policy putting more weight on growth and employment than on inflation. And while the recent rise in energy prices will cut into household spending on discretionary goods and services, the magnitude of the rise needs to be kept in perspective. In comparison to the ten-fold increase in nominal crude oil prices during the oil shocks of the 1970s, this year prices have risen just 70 percent, less than double their starting point. The inflationary impact of this rise will be measured in tens of basis points, not full percentage points. Further, even with strong inflation this year, real personal income excluding government transfer payments has roughly returned to pre-crisis levels. And high levels of household savings, due in part to those transfer payments, should support household spending for the foreseeable future. Strong labor demand should support spending as well.

Figure 3: Real Household Income Excluding Government Transfer Payments

If the 1950s and early 1960s, with its combination of strong growth and firm inflation, is a better analogy for the years ahead, it raises the question of how well the Federal Reserve can manage the associated risks. As noted in a previous report, if inflation shows signs of persisting above policymakers’ comfort level, it could set the stage for more forceful policy tightening over the medium term. Unfortunately, the FOMC’s track record of cooling off a hot economy and engineering a soft landing is less than stellar. Historically, when the economy slows and the unemployment rate rises by half a percentage point over the span of a year, a recession has invariably followed. And if that recession comes with inflation still running strong, there’s a significant risk of at least a short period of stagflation.

Figure 4: One-Year Change in Unemployment Rate

IMPORTANT DISCLOSURE

Availability of this document and products and services provided by MacKay Shields LLC and/or MacKay Shields Europe Investment Management Limited (collectively, “MacKay Shields”) may be limited by applicable laws and regulations in certain jurisdictions and this document is provided only for persons to whom this document and the products and services of MacKay Shields may otherwise lawfully be issued or made available. None of the products and services provided by MacKay Shields are offered to any person in any jurisdiction where such offering would be contrary to local law or regulation. This document is provided for informational purposes only. It does not constitute investment advice and should not be construed as an offer to buy securities. The contents of this document have not been reviewed by any regulatory authority in any jurisdiction.

This material contains the opinions of certain professionals at MacKay Shields and are subject to change without notice. Forecasts, estimates, and opinions contained herein should not be considered as investment advice or a recommendation of any particular security, strategy or investment product. Information contained herein has been obtained from sources believed to be reliable, but not guaranteed. Any forward-looking statements speak only as of the date they are made and MacKay Shields assumes no duty and does not undertake to update forward-looking statements. No part of this document may be reproduced in any form, or referred to in any other publication, without express written permission of MacKay Shields LLC.

Past performance is not indicative of future results.

©2022, MacKay Shields LLC. All Rights Reserved.

To obtain entire/whole article, including full disclosures and source attribution which must be read with and form the complete version of the above commentary, please select “Download Article” above.

     

Subscribe to get MacKay Shields insights delivered to your inbox.